Recent Trends in Wages, Incomes, and Wealth in the United States
D R A F T
John Schmitt, Lawrence Mishel, and Jared Bernstein
Paper prepared for panel on "Trends in Economic Well-being in North
America, Canadian Economic Association Meetings, Ottawa, May 31, 1998
I. Introduction
This paper reviews recent evidence on the level and distribution of wages,
income, and wealth in the United States. The principal focus is on how
these three measures of economic well-being have changed over the current
business-cycle recovery.
The principal findings for the 1990s are:
-
Wage inequality increased between 1989 and 1997, but at a slower pace than
it did between 1979 and 1989.
-
Increases in the federal minimum wage in 1990, 1991, 1996, and 1997, and
low unemployment, especially in 1997, seem to have played an important
role in retarding and eventually reversing the long-standing decline in
wages for workers at bottom of the wage distribution.
-
At the median and at the 90th percentile, wage growth was slower in 1989-97
than it was in 1979-89.
-
Over the period 1989-97, even those workers at the 90th percentile and
those with a four-year college degree saw their wages, on average, lag
behind growth in average economy-wide productivity.
-
Family income inequality grew sharply between 1989 and 1996, with the Gini
coefficient rising from 0.401 to 0.425.
-
Over the 1989-96 period, family incomes were flat or falling in real terms
for the bottom four quintiles of the family-income distribution; the share
of the bottom four quintiles in total family income fell 2.2 percentage
points.
-
Between 1989 and 1996, the share of persons in poverty increased from 12.8%
to 13.7%.
-
Household wealth inequality rose significantly between 1989 and 1997, driven
in part by the bouyant U.S. stock market.
-
While direct and indirect stock holdings have become much more widely distributed,
the value of stock holdings for the vast majority is relatively small.
The middle quintile of the wealth distribution, for example, owned about
$7,500 in stock in all forms in 1997; the bottom 40% held an average of
about $1,500
II. The Data
We employ three main sources of data. For hourly wages, we use on the Current
Population Survey’s (CPS) Outgoing Rotation Group (ORG) for the years 1979-97.
This is a one-quarter sample of the full CPS, which surveys about 55,000
households. Prior to 1979, we draw comparable wage data from the May CPS,
which contains questions about wages and salaries at the respondent’s current
job. Our sample includes all wage and salary workers ages 18 to 64. 1
For annual family income, we report results of the Bureau of Census’s
analyses of the March CPS, which asks respondents detailed questions about
their earnings in the preceding calendar year. Due to lags in the analysis
and release of these data, the most recently available family-income data
are for 1996. For wealth, we rely on analyses of the Survey of Consumer
Finance (SCF) conducted by Ed Wolff (1998a, 1998b). The SCF is an irregular,
detailed, survey conducted by the Federal Reserve Bank of households’ financial
assets and liabilities. The most recent survey covers 1995, but Wolff (1998b)
has used the 1995 SCF data and more recent data from other sources to produce
projections of the basic distribution through 1997.
We have converted all nominal values to real 1997 dollars using the
CPI-U-X1 series. The CPI-U-X1 corrects the official CPI for problems in
house prices prior to 1982. Since the Bureau of Labor Statistics has not
produced a CPI-U-X1 series prior to 1967, we deflate earlier years using
a series created by chaining the pre-1967 CPI to CPI-U-X1.
III. Wages
A. Overall Distribution
Tables 1A, 1B, and 1C
summarize developments in the hourly wage distribution
between 1973 and 1997. Table 1A shows the real hourly wage in 1997 dollars
for the 10th, 50th, and 90th percentile of all wage and salary workers,
ages 18 to 64. The data cover the years 1973, 1979, 1989 (all cyclical
peaks, defined by low-points in the national unemployment rate) and each
year in the 1990s through 1997, a year with a national unemployment rate
that is probably close to the lowest level to be achieved in the current
business cycle. For the 1980s, the table tells the now-familiar story of
declining real wages for workers at the middle and the bottom of the wage
distribution. Between 1979 and 1989, real wages of workers at the 10th
percentile fell at a 1.6% annualized rate between; at the median, real
wages declined an average 0.2% per year over the same period. (The table
also demonstrates another, less-widely commented, aspect of the 1980s wage
distribution: even at the 90th percentile real wages grew little over the
period --from $22.46 per hour in 1979 to $23.46 per hour in 1989, an annualized
growth rate of just 0.4% per year.)
Table 1A also shows the year-to-year changes in wages over the decade
of the 1990s. The most striking development over the current business-cycle
is the reversal of fortune of low-wage workers, with real wages at the
10th percentile rising on average 0.2% per year between 1989
and 1997, up considerably from the 1.6% per year decline for 1979-89. A
closer look at the pattern of wage changes suggests that a combination
of increases in the federal minimum wage and low unemployment may have
helped to boost wages at the bottom. Real wages at the 10th percentile
rose in only three of the eight years in 1990s: 1990, 1991, and 1997. These
are all years when the federal minimum wage increased (in 1990 from $3.35
per hour to $3.80; in 1991, to $4.25; in 1997, to $.4.75). While the federal
minimum wage lies below the 10th percentile wage in all three years, even
modest spillover effects could explain the small increases at the 10th
percentile. 2 The data for 1997 suggest an independent role for low unemployment
in explaining real wage growth at the bottom. In 1990 and 1991, as unemployment
increased, real wages at the 10th percentile grew about 1.1% per year;
in 1997, as unemployment fell 0.5% to below 5.0%, real wages at the 10th
percentile increased at a much faster 3.2% annual rate. 3
A second feature of the 1990s is the worsening performance of
real wages at the middle and the top. Between 1989 and 1997, the median
real wage fell at twice the rate it did in the 1980s (-0.4% compared to
-0.2%). Over the same period, real wage growth at the 90th percentile decelerated
from 0.4% to 0.2% per year. At the median, real wages were generally flat
through the recession in 1992 and then, perversely, fell continuously over
the recovery from 1993 through 1996. In 1997, however, real median wages
grew 2.2%. At the 90th percentile, no clear pattern emerges, with real
wages rising and falling over much of the period, ending with a 1.5% increase
between 1996 and 1997. The deterioration in performance at the middle and
the top together with the rise in real wages at the bottom mean that the
rise in overall wage inequality has decelerated during the current business
cycle, with wage inequality (defined by the 90-10 differential) actually
declining between 1994 and 1997.
A final feature of the data in Table 1A is the failure of the vast majority
of workers to keep pace with average productivity after 1973. The median
hourly wage fell 0.2-0.4% per year after 1973, while average productivity
grew at about a 1.0% annual rate (see Appendix Table 1). Even at the 90th
percentile, annual wage growth ranged between 0.2-0.4%, still well below
the average gain in labor productivity.
Tables 1B and 1C show the same real wage data separately for men and
women. These data demonstrate another well-documented pattern: while women’s
wages remain below men’s wages at comparable positions in the respective
wage distributions, over the last 25 years or so, women’s wages have generally
grown more rapidly than those of men. Table 1B demonstrates that men’s
wages at the 10th percentile have been following continuously
over the business cycles of the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s. The decline in
male wages at the bottom was strongest in the 1980s (-1.3% per year), but
the deterioration has continued, albeit at a slower pace, in the 1990s
(-0.5% per year). At the median, male wages fell rapidly through both the
1980s (-0.9% per year) and the 1990s (-0.8% per year). Male wages at the
90th percentile were virtually stagnant over the entire 1973-97
period, growing at annualized rate little more than 0.1% per year. For
women (see Table 1C), wage developments were generally better. Women at
the 10th percentile saw rapid real wage increases in the 1970s
(3.6% per year); steep declines (worse than for men at the 10th
percentile) in the 1980s (-1.8% per year); and a considerable recovery
over the 1990s (0.3% per year). Women’s median wages have risen over the
three business cycles, most rapidly in the 1980s (0.6% per year) and much
less rapidly in the 1990s (0.1% per year), far outperforming men at the
median over the same time periods. Women at the 90th percentile
posted the highest wage increases of any group, with a 1.6% per year increase
in the 1980s and a 0.8% increase per year in the 1990s.
B. Real Wages By Education Level
Since much of the discussion of rising wage inequality during the 1980s
and 1990s has focused on the role of formal education as a proxy for workers’
broader "skill" levels, we present wage data by education level in Tables
2A, 2B, and 2C. Again, much of the story is familiar. Wages for less-educated
workers (see Table 2A), whether male (see Table 2B) or female (see Table
2C) have all declined in the 1980s and the 1990s. Discussions of wage trends
over the last two decades, however, have not fully addressed another important
feature of the data in the tables. The real wage declines extend far beyond
those workers with the lowest level of formal education (less-than-high-school-educated
workers), who account for about 15% of the total workforce. Real wages
have also fallen for the 40% or so of the U.S. workforce with a terminal
high school degree and the 20% or so of the workforce with one-to-three
years towards a four-year college degree. Even the real wages of workers
with a four-year college degree (but no further education) –about a 15%
of the workforce— have seen real wage increases at (in the case of women)
or below (in the case of men) the average increase in productivity over
the period. The only education group that has done consistently well over
the last two decades are those with advanced degrees (just over 5% of the
workforce). 4
Using the education breakdown, the real wage pattern in the year-to-year
data in the 1990s differs somewhat from that in the overall distribution.
In the overall distribution, wage increases during the 1990s were largest
at the bottom. By education level, where all the average wage levels are
well above the 10th percentile wage, wages grew slowest at the
bottom of the educational distribution and most quickly at the middle and
the top. Even in the boom year of 1997, the real wages of less-than-high-school-educated
workers, for example, did not change. Over the same period, real wages
increases rose for all better-educated workers (high-school, 1.7%; some
college, 2.1%; college, 2.9%; and, college plus, 1.1%).
C. Poverty-Level Wages
Widening wage inequality with stagnant and declining wages, on the one
hand, and apparently rapid rates of job creation, 5 on the other, gave rise
in the 1990s to the view that the jobs being created in the U.S. economy
were of poor quality. In the spring of 1996, the Council of Economic Advisors
(1996) entered the debate with an influential study of the quality of job
creation between February 1994 and February 1996. Since the U.S. government
does not collect data on "new" jobs, 6 the CEA divided respondents to the
CPS into about 400 industry-occupation categories. The CEA then calculated
the median wage in each industry-occupation category in 1994 as well as
the total employment in each category in both 1994 and 1996. The CEA used
changes in the estimated total employment in each of the categories over
the two-year period to identify where the "new jobs" were being created.
The CEA finally compared the 1994-96 job creation data with the 1994 wage
data to see whether the net job creation was occuring in high-wage or low-wage
industry-occupation categories. The CEA concluded that most of the jobs
were being created in industry-occupation categories where the median wage
was above the median for the economy as a whole. Another recent study,
by Ilg (1997), uses a similar methodology with more recent data to arrive
at a similar conclusion.
We have several objections to this approach. First, neither the CEA
nor Ilg examined how wages in their categories changed over the
same periods that they examine employment changes. An analysis of Ilg’s
data, for example, shows that while job growth was indeed strongest in
those categories where the median wage was above the national median, the
median real wage also fell in every job category, including those
that paid above the national median. Second, the approach is at best indirect,
since we can never observe new jobs, but only infer, where, on net they
are being created. That the median real wage is falling across categories
suggests that the new jobs may be below the median for the category and
are therefore not necessarily themselves above the national median. Third,
the approach focuses too much attention on net job creation, which has
averaged only 1.2% per year in the 1990s, rather than on gross job creation,
which has probably been about 20 times larger on an annual basis (just
slightly higher than gross job destruction). 7 Even if the CEA analysis could
clearly demonstrate that the net new jobs being created in the economy
were "good jobs", 8 the vast majority of the gross new jobs created could
still be of poorer quality than the gross old jobs destroyed. This final
point can be taken one step further. In slightly imprecise terms, it is
difficult to explain large changes in the wage distribution by concentrating
on the 1% or so of new jobs created each year, while ignoring what is happening
to the "other 99%" of jobs. Our own view is that the deterioration in the
U.S. wage structure since the end of the 1970s is not primarily a function
of the quality of new jobs created, on net, since that time. Rather, the
principal problem stems from the institutional changes in the labor market
that have undermined the bargaining power of workers in the vast majority
of "existing jobs".
Given the problems with approaches based on the wage levels of new jobs,
and our own concern with what is happening across the entire stock of jobs,
we prefer to examine "job quality" using the approach outlined in Table 3.
We have converted the wage distributions for 1973, 1979, 1989, and 1997
into real 1997 dollars and then grouped workers in each year into categories
based on ratios of the 1997 "poverty-level wage" (the hourly wage rate
necessary to earn the federal poverty-level for a family of four if a worker
works 40 hours per week, 52 weeks per year). The data for men and women
together (see panel (a)) show that jobs paying "poverty-level" wages or
less jumped markedly between the 1970s (about 23.6%) and 1989 (28.5%).
The number of poverty level jobs, however, had not changed much by 1997
(28.6%). Between 1989 and 1997, jobs paying just above the poverty-level
wage (100-125%) grew slightly as did those paying 300% or more of the poverty-level
wage. This cut of the data suggests that the overall wage distribution
is shifting simultaneously toward both lower-paying and higher-paying jobs.
The patterns for men (panel (b)) and women (panel (c)) separately show
important differences. Poverty-level jobs for men increase across every
business cycle peak from 1973 though 1997. In the 1990s, the share of men
holding a job paying below the poverty-level wage grew from 21.2% to 22.5%
of male employment. The share earning near-poverty-level wages (100-125%)
also increased. At the same time, the share of men earning 200-300% and
300% or more of the poverty-level wage fell a combined 3.6 percentage points.
While many more women than men earned poverty level wages in 1997 (35.3%
of women compared to 22.5% of men), the share of women earning low-wages
fell over the 1990s business cycle, as did the share earning near-poverty-level
wages. Over the same period, women also saw a 1.8 percentage-point rise
in the share earning 300% or more of the poverty-level wage. The gains
for women in the 1990s, however, are mixed compared to the 1980s. The increase
in the share of women earning high wages was much more rapid in the 1980s
than in the 1990s. At the same time, the 1990s saw some improvement in
the composition within the lowest-paid categories, after a dramatic increase
in the 1980s in the share of women in the lowest wage category (0-75% of
the poverty-level wage).
IV. Incomes
A. Overall Distribution
The distribution of family income in the United States grew more equal
between 1947 and 1973. Table 4 demonstrates that between 1947 and 1967,
the share of family income going to each quintile grew for the bottom four
quintiles and declined for the top quintile. Meanwhile, the Gini coefficient
fell from 0.376 to 0.358. The data in Table 5, which looks at the annual
income of families at the 20th, 40th, 60th,
80th, and 95th percentiles, show that, across the
board, family-income growth was strong, but skewed slightly in favor of
less well-off families in the 1947-67 period. Annual growth rates in family
income, for example varied from 2.8-2.9% for the 20th and 40th
percentile families to 2.5% for the 95th percentile family.
Between 1967 and 1973, family income continued to grow rapidly (between
2.2% and 3.0% per year), but families at the bottom experienced the slowest
growth.
After 1973, growth in family income decelerated and grew more unequal.
The share of the bottom two quintiles in the total family income fell over
the 1973-79, 1979-89, and 1989-96 cycles; the share of the bottom four
quintiles declined in 1979-89 and 1989-96. The 1990s produced what is arguably
the worst family income figures for the postwar period. Between 1989 and
1996, real family incomes fell at the 20th, 40th,
and 60th percentile; were flat at the 80th percentile;
and grew at just a 0.3% annual rate at the 95th percentile.
Over the same period, the annual growth rate in average income (0.3%) was
the slowest in any postwar business cycle. The income share of each of
the bottom four fifths of families declined, while the share of the top
fifth in total income grew 2.2 percentage points. The year-to-year numbers
for the 1990s show the typical cyclical pattern in family income. At the
20th, 40th, and 60th percentiles, family
incomes fall through 1993 and then recover continuously through 1996. Growth
rates at these same percentiles, however, are actually slower in 1996 than
they were in 1995. At the 80th and 95th percentiles,
real income hits bottom earlier (1991 for the 95th percentile,
1992 for the 80th) and recovers more strongly through the rest
of the cycle.
B. Poverty Rate
One important aspect of the income distribution is the share of persons
living in poverty. Table 6 reports the poverty rates for selected years
between 1967 and 1996 according to two definitions of poverty. The first
definition is the official U.S. government poverty rate, which is based
on a minimum consumption basket established in the 1960s. The second definition
is based on a relative poverty measure that is more typical for international
comparisons. According to the official definition, poverty dropped sharply
between 1967 and 1973 and then grew continuously over the business cycle
peaks in 1979, 1989, and 1996. The cyclical pattern of poverty rates is
obvious in the yearly data for the 1990s. Poverty grows uninterruptedly
between the cyclical peak in 1989 through the cyclical trough in 1992 and
even into the "jobless recovery" in 1994. Poverty then fell in 1995 and
by a smaller amount in 1996.
Table 6 also allows us to compare the official poverty rate with a common
alternative definition based on relative incomes. Using the broadest measure
of relative poverty --the share in families receiving less than half of
the median income-- the poverty rate increases substantially between 1973
and 1979 and again between 1979 and 1989, but changes little over the decade
of the 1990s. The broad definition puts about 22% of the population in
poverty in the 1990s, above the 13-15% official rate over the same years.
A narrower definition --those receiving less than one-fourth of the national
median increases significantly between 1979 and 1989 (from 6.7% to 8.3%),
and then by a smaller amount between 1989 and 1996 (from 8.3% to 8.6%).
V. Wealth
A. Overall Distribution
Unfortunately, the Survey of Consumer Finance, which is the underlying
source of the wealth data in Tables 8 and 9, is not an annual survey. We
therefore cannot report the distributions for the peak years as in previous
tables. Instead, we will concentrate on general characteristics of the
distribution and how the distribution changed between 1989 and 1997 (using
Wolff’s projections for the latter year).
Table 7 demonstrates that the wealth distribution is more unequal than
either the wage or income distribution. The share of wealth held by the
top quintile has been above 80% in every survey year since 1962, with the
share increasing slightly in each survey. Even within the top quintile,
wealth is heavily concentrated in the top one percent of the full distribution,
which controls more than one-third of all wealth.
Table 8, panel (d), attaches dollar figures to the share figures in
Table 7. In 1997, the estimated average net worth (assets minus liabilities)
of the top one percent of households was about $9.5 million compared to
about $53,400 in the middle quintile, and to just $3,100 among the least
wealthy 40% of households. Between 1989 and 1997, net worth for the top
one percent grew by almost $1 million; declined about $1,600 in the middle
quintile; and grew about $6,900 for the bottom 40% (from a negative net
worth of -$3,800 to a positive net worth of $3,100).
B. Stock Market Boom
Table 8 also demonstrates the impact of the recent stock market boom
on the overall wealth distribution. Panel (a) shows the gross value of
direct and indirect stock holdings across the household wealth distribution.
Between 1989 and 1997, the value of stock held by the top one percent of
households rose $1.2 million, from about $1.1 million to about $2.3 million.
In dollar terms, the level and growth in stock holdings were much smaller
for the bottom 80% of households. The average stock holdings in the fourth
quintile (from the 61st to the 80th percentile),
for example, grew from $8,300 in 1989 to $18,600 in 1997. For households
in the middle quintile, average stock holdings grew from $3,500 to $7,500.
Households in the bottom 40% of the wealth distribution saw their holdings
more than double – from about $600 to $1,500.
VI. Conclusions
The current business cycle has enjoyed both relatively low unemployment
and low inflation rates. By 1997, low unemployment, in combination with
four increases in the federal minimum wage, appears to have helped to reverse
part of the long-term decline in real hourly wages for workers at the 10th
percentile of the wage distribution. The improved prospects for low-wage
workers, together with a deterioration in wage growth for workers in the
midde and top of the wage distribution, have led to a deceleration in wage
inequality in the 1990s compared to the 1980s. Since 1994, overall wage
inequality has actually declined.
Nevertheless, large problems remain and some have even grown worse in
the 1990s. Wages in the middle and top of the wage distribution have grown
more slowly over the current cycle than they did in the 1970s or 1980s.
The distribution of family income, at least through 1996, has grown more
unequal, with the bottom four fifths of the distribution experiencing stagnant
or declining real incomes over the period. Not surprisingly, given the
family income trends, the poverty rate rose from 12.8% to 13.7% between
1989 and 1996. Finally, the already highly unequal distribution of wealth
grew even more unequal between 1989 and 1997, in part, as a function of
a stock market boom, whose benefits are still rather narrowly confined.
Endnotes
1 For a complete description of the CPS wage data, see Webster (1997).
2 The combined 1990-91 increases, for example, raised the minimum
wage about 24% in nominal terms. Real wages at the 10th percentile grew
about 1.1% in both years. The decline in 10th percentile real wages, despite
a rise in the federal minimum wage in 1996, however, argues against the
importance of the minimum wage.
3 A preliminary analysis of CPS ORG wage data for 1998, a year
in which unemployment continued to fall, also suggests an important role
for unemployment in the determination of wages at the 10th percentile.
4 Education shares are approximate and refer to 1989. For a more
detailed breakdown, see Mishel, Bernstein, and Schmitt (1997), Tables 3.18,
3.19, and 3.20.
5 Job creation rates over the current business cycle (about 1.2%
per year between 1989 and 1997) are slow even by recent historical standards.
Job creation rates averaged 1.7% between 1979 and 1989, and 2.5% between
1973 and 1979.
6 U.S. government employment numbers generally come from two sources:
the Current Population Survey, which interviews individuals in noninstitutional
households; and the Bureau of Labor Statistics' Establishment Survey, which
asks establishments about overall staffing levels.
7 See Davis, Haltiwanger, and Schuh (1996).
8 This would involve answering the sticky question about which
of the "gross new jobs" were "net new" ones.
APPENDIX TABLE 1
Macroeconomic Indicators, 1947-97
Year |
Unemployment
Rate
%
|
Real
GDP
(1992$ billions)
|
Nonfarm Labor
Productivity
(1992=100)
|
1947 |
3.9 |
1,463.4 |
36.6 |
1967 |
3.8
|
3,147.2
|
69.2
|
1973 |
4.9
|
3,916.3
|
80.7
|
1979 |
5.8
|
4,630.6
|
86.3
|
1989 |
5.3
|
6,062.0
|
95.7
|
1990 |
5.6
|
6,136.3
|
96.2
|
1991 |
6.8
|
6,079.4
|
96.9
|
1992 |
7.5
|
6,244.4
|
100.0
|
1993 |
6.9
|
6,389.6
|
100.1
|
1994 |
6.1
|
6,610.7
|
100.5
|
1995 |
5.6
|
6,742.1
|
100.7
|
1996 |
5.4
|
6,928.4
|
102.0
|
1997* |
4.9
|
7,191.4
|
103.5
|
Change |
Percentage-Point
|
Annualized Percent Change
|
1947-67 |
-0.1
|
3.9
|
3.2
|
1967-73 |
1.1
|
3.7
|
2.6
|
1973-79 |
0.9
|
2.8
|
1.1
|
1979-89 |
-0.5
|
2.7
|
1.0
|
1989-97 |
-0.4
|
2.2
|
1.0
|
*Productivity figure is for the first
3 quarters.
Source: Economic Report of the President
(1985, 1998).
TABLE 1A
Real Hourly Wages, All Workers 18-64, 1973-97
(1997 Dollars)
Year |
Percentile
|
10th
|
50th
|
90th
|
1973 |
6.07
|
11.61
|
22.22
|
1979 |
6.42
|
11.46
|
22.46
|
1989 |
5.39
|
11.18
|
23.46
|
1990 |
5.45
|
11.12
|
23.48
|
1991 |
5.52
|
11.12
|
23.49
|
1992 |
5.49
|
11.16
|
23.07
|
1993 |
5.44
|
11.03
|
23.33
|
1994 |
5.36
|
10.79
|
23.64
|
1995 |
5.33
|
10.67
|
23.54
|
1996 |
5.29
|
10.59
|
23.54
|
1997 |
5.46
|
10.82
|
23.90
|
Annualized
Percent Change |
1973-79 |
1.0
|
-0.2
|
0.2
|
1979-89 |
-1.6
|
-0.2
|
0.4
|
1989-97 |
0.2
|
-0.4
|
0.2
|
Source: Authors' analysis of CPS ORG data;
inflation-adjusted using CPI-U-X1.
TABLE 1B
Real Hourly Wages, Men 18-64, 1973-97
(1997 Dollars)
Year |
Percentile
|
10th
|
50th
|
90th
|
1973 |
7.16
|
14.08
|
25.74
|
1979 |
7.07
|
14.39
|
25.93
|
1989 |
6.17
|
13.07
|
26.12
|
1990 |
6.05
|
12.82
|
26.52
|
1991 |
5.91
|
12.71
|
26.28
|
1992 |
5.79
|
12.54
|
26.16
|
1993 |
5.72
|
12.37
|
26.34
|
1994 |
5.67
|
12.11
|
26.19
|
1995 |
5.78
|
12.24
|
26.20
|
1996 |
5.81
|
12.12
|
25.85
|
1997 |
5.92
|
12.19
|
26.44
|
Annualized
Percent Change |
1973-79 |
-0.2
|
0.4
|
0.1
|
1979-89 |
-1.3
|
-0.9
|
0.1
|
1989-97 |
-0.5
|
-0.8
|
0.2
|
Source: Authors' analysis of CPS ORG data;
inflation-adjusted using CPI-U-X1.
TABLE 1C
Real Hourly Wages, Women 18-64, 1973-97
(1997 Dollars)
Year |
Percentile
|
10th
|
50th
|
90th
|
1973 |
5.05
|
8.89
|
16.07
|
1979 |
6.13
|
9.03
|
16.62
|
1989 |
5.02
|
9.55
|
19.33
|
1990 |
5.05
|
9.54
|
19.35
|
1991 |
5.13
|
9.52
|
19.66
|
1992 |
5.20
|
9.55
|
20.00
|
1993 |
5.20
|
9.61
|
20.15
|
1994 |
5.14
|
9.49
|
20.46
|
1995 |
5.10
|
9.39
|
20.19
|
1996 |
5.07
|
9.41
|
20.36
|
1997 |
5.15
|
9.63
|
20.61
|
Annualized
Percent Change |
1973-79 |
3.6
|
0.3
|
0.6
|
1979-89 |
-1.8
|
0.6
|
1.6
|
1989-97 |
0.3
|
0.1
|
0.8
|
Source: Authors' analysis of CPS ORG data;
inflation-adjusted using CPI-U-X1.
TABLE 2A
Real Hourly Wages, By Education* Level, All Workers
18-64, 1973-97
(1997 Dollars)
Year |
Less Than
High School
|
High School
|
Some
College
|
College
|
College Plus
|
College/
High School |
1973 |
11.22
|
12.82
|
14.16
|
18.60
|
22.66
|
1.45
|
1979 |
11.15
|
12.49
|
13.61
|
17.43
|
21.42
|
1.40
|
1989 |
9.38
|
11.36
|
13.20
|
17.88
|
23.24
|
1.57
|
1990 |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
1991 |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
1992 |
8.86
|
11.07
|
12.52
|
18.04
|
23.03
|
1.63
|
1993 |
8.72
|
11.02
|
12.47
|
17.97
|
23.22
|
1.63
|
1994 |
8.52
|
11.10
|
12.36
|
18.14
|
24.17
|
1.63
|
1995 |
8.25
|
10.90
|
12.20
|
18.13
|
23.90
|
1.66
|
1996 |
8.21
|
10.84
|
12.18
|
17.86
|
23.80
|
1.65
|
1997 |
8.22
|
11.02
|
12.43
|
18.38
|
24.07
|
1.67
|
Annualized
Percent Change |
1973-79 |
-0.1
|
-0.4
|
-0.7
|
-1.0
|
-0.9
|
  |
1979-89 |
-1.6
|
-0.9
|
-0.3
|
0.3
|
0.9
|
  |
1989-97 |
-1.5
|
-0.4
|
-0.7
|
0.3
|
0.4
|
  |
*Education levels from 1992-1997 are estimates
designed to be consistent with pre-1992 educational coding.
Source: Authors' analysis of CPS ORG
data; inflation-adjusted using CPI-U-X1.
TABLE 2B
Real Hourly Wages, By Education* Level, Men 18-64,
1973-97
(1997 Dollars)
Year |
Less Than
High School
|
High School
|
Some
College
|
College
|
College Plus
|
College/
High School |
1973 |
13.11
|
15.43
|
16.25
|
21.40
|
23.82
|
1.39
|
1979 |
12.87
|
15.01
|
15.94
|
20.46
|
23.33
|
1.36
|
1989 |
10.63
|
13.17
|
15.03
|
20.58
|
25.73
|
1.56
|
1990 |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
1991 |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
1992 |
9.80
|
12.58
|
14.04
|
20.45
|
25.61
|
1.63
|
1993 |
9.60
|
12.45
|
13.93
|
20.33
|
25.77
|
1.63
|
1994 |
9.31
|
12.51
|
13.85
|
20.45
|
26.47
|
1.63
|
1995 |
9.07
|
12.31
|
13.74
|
20.43
|
26.45
|
1.66
|
1996 |
9.04
|
12.22
|
13.68
|
20.21
|
26.21
|
1.65
|
1997 |
9.01
|
12.48
|
14.00
|
20.78
|
26.62
|
1.67
|
Annualized
Percent Change |
1973-79 |
-0.3
|
-0.5
|
-0.3
|
-0.7
|
-0.3
|
  |
1979-89 |
-1.7
|
-1.2
|
-0.6
|
0.1
|
1.0
|
  |
1989-97 |
-1.9
|
-0.7
|
-0.9
|
0.1
|
0.4
|
  |
*Education levels from 1992-1997 are estimates
designed to be consistent with pre-1992 educational coding.
Source: Authors' analysis of CPS ORG
data; inflation-adjusted using CPI-U-X1.
TABLE 2C
Real Hourly Wages, By Education* Level, Women 18-64,
1973-97
(1997 Dollars)
Year |
Less Than
High School
|
High School
|
Some
College
|
College
|
College Plus
|
College/
High School |
1973 |
7.91
|
9.75
|
10.86
|
14.43
|
19.40
|
1.48
|
1979 |
8.26
|
9.77
|
10.70
|
13.08
|
17.05
|
1.34
|
1989 |
7.37
|
9.50
|
11.36
|
14.77
|
19.49
|
1.55
|
1990 |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
1991 |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
1992 |
7.38
|
9.49
|
11.05
|
15.40
|
19.55
|
1.62
|
1993 |
7.31
|
9.50
|
11.08
|
15.41
|
19.84
|
1.62
|
1994 |
7.22
|
9.57
|
10.95
|
15.59
|
21.18
|
1.63
|
1995 |
6.92
|
9.36
|
10.73
|
15.61
|
20.55
|
1.67
|
1996 |
6.85
|
9.32
|
10.76
|
15.41
|
20.69
|
1.65
|
1997 |
6.94
|
9.44
|
10.92
|
15.89
|
20.87
|
1.68
|
Annualized
Percent Change. |
1973-79 |
0.7
|
0.0
|
-0.2
|
-1.6
|
-2.0
|
  |
1979-89 |
-1.1
|
-0.3
|
0.6
|
1.3
|
1.4
|
  |
1989-97 |
-0.7
|
-0.1
|
-0.5
|
0.9
|
0.9
|
  |
*Education levels from 1992-1997 are estimates
designed to be consistent with pre-1992 educational coding.
Source: Authors' analysis of CPS ORG
data; inflation-adjusted using CPI-U-X1.
TABLE 3
Distribution of Total Employment by Real Wage Level,
1973-97
(Share of Employment in Percent)
Year |
Poverty-Level Wages
|
100-125
|
125-200
|
200-300
|
300+
|
Total
|
0-75
|
75-100
|
Total
|
(a)
All |
1973 |
8.0
|
15.6
|
23.5
|
13.3
|
34.7
|
19.9
|
8.6
|
100.0
|
1979 |
4.2
|
19.4
|
23.7
|
15.3
|
31.4
|
21.0
|
8.7
|
100.0
|
1989 |
13.4
|
15.1
|
28.5
|
13.5
|
29.2
|
19.1
|
9.7
|
100.0
|
1997 |
12.1
|
16.5
|
28.6
|
14.1
|
29.6
|
17.3
|
10.3
|
100.0
|
Percentage-Point
Change |
1973-79 |
-3.7
|
3.9
|
0.1
|
2.0
|
-3.3
|
1.1
|
0.0
|
  |
1979-89 |
9.2
|
-4.3
|
4.9
|
-1.8
|
-2.2
|
-1.9
|
1.0
|
  |
1989-97 |
-1.3
|
1.3
|
0.1
|
0.6
|
0.4
|
-1.7
|
0.7
|
  |
(b)
Men |
1973 |
3.8
|
9.0
|
12.8
|
9.7
|
36.7
|
27.9
|
12.9
|
100.0
|
1979 |
2.4
|
11.0
|
13.4
|
11.3
|
32.1
|
29.6
|
13.6
|
100.0
|
1989 |
9.1
|
12.1
|
21.2
|
11.3
|
29.7
|
23.7
|
14.1
|
100.0
|
1997 |
8.8
|
13.7
|
22.5
|
12.6
|
30.6
|
20.5
|
13.8
|
100.0
|
Percentage-Point
Change |
1973-79 |
-1.5
|
2.1
|
0.6
|
1.6
|
-4.6
|
1.7
|
0.6
|
  |
1979-89 |
6.8
|
1.1
|
7.8
|
0.0
|
-2.5
|
-5.9
|
0.5
|
  |
1989-97 |
-0.3
|
1.6
|
1.3
|
1.3
|
0.9
|
-3.2
|
-0.3
|
  |
(c)
Women |
1973 |
14.0
|
25.1
|
39.1
|
18.6
|
31.7
|
8.3
|
2.3
|
100.0
|
1979 |
6.7
|
30.4
|
37.0
|
20.5
|
30.4
|
9.8
|
2.3
|
100.0
|
1989 |
18.2
|
18.6
|
36.8
|
16.0
|
28.6
|
13.8
|
4.7
|
100.0
|
1997 |
15.7
|
19.5
|
35.3
|
15.8
|
28.5
|
13.9
|
6.6
|
100.0
|
Percentage-Point
Change |
1973-79 |
-7.3
|
5.3
|
-2.1
|
1.9
|
-1.2
|
1.5
|
0.0
|
  |
1979-89 |
11.6
|
-11.8
|
-0.3
|
-4.5
|
-1.8
|
4.1
|
2.5
|
  |
1989-97 |
-2.5
|
1.0
|
-1.5
|
-0.3
|
-0.1
|
0.0
|
1.8
|
  |
Source: Authors' analysis of CPS ORG data;
inflation-adjusted using CPI-U-X1.
TABLE 4
Distribution of Family Income, 1947-96
(Percent of All Families)
Year |
Lowest
Fifth
|
Second
Fifth
|
Middle
Fifth
|
Fourth
Fifth
|
Top
Fifth
|
Top 5%
|
Gini
Coefficient
|
1947 |
5.0
|
11.9
|
17.0
|
23.1
|
43.0
|
17.5
|
0.376
|
1967 |
5.4
|
12.2
|
17.5
|
23.5
|
41.4
|
16.4
|
0.358
|
1973 |
5.5
|
11.9
|
17.5
|
24.0
|
41.1
|
15.5
|
0.356
|
1979 |
5.4
|
11.6
|
17.5
|
24.1
|
41.4
|
15.3
|
0.365
|
1989 |
4.6
|
10.6
|
16.5
|
23.7
|
44.6
|
17.9
|
0.401
|
1990 |
4.6
|
10.8
|
16.6
|
23.8
|
44.3
|
17.4
|
  |
1991 |
4.5
|
10.7
|
16.6
|
24.1
|
44.2
|
17.1
|
  |
1992 |
4.3
|
10.5
|
16.5
|
24.0
|
44.7
|
17.6
|
  |
1993 |
4.1
|
9.9
|
15.7
|
23.3
|
47.0
|
20.3
|
  |
1994 |
4.2
|
10.0
|
15.7
|
23.3
|
46.9
|
20.1
|
  |
1995 |
4.4
|
10.1
|
15.8
|
23.2
|
46.5
|
20.0
|
  |
1996* |
4.2
|
10.0
|
15.8
|
23.1
|
46.8
|
20.3
|
0.425
|
Percentage-point
Change |
1947-67 |
0.4
|
0.3
|
0.5
|
0.4
|
-1.6
|
-1.1
|
  |
1967-73 |
0.1
|
-0.3
|
0.0
|
0.5
|
-0.3
|
-0.9
|
  |
1973-79 |
-0.1
|
-0.3
|
0.0
|
0.1
|
0.3
|
-0.2
|
  |
1979-89 |
-0.8
|
-1.0
|
-1.0
|
-0.4
|
3.2
|
2.6
|
  |
1989-96 |
-0.4
|
-0.6
|
-0.7
|
-0.6
|
2.2
|
2.4
|
  |
*These shares allow the top-code to increase
and thus show greater inequality.
Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census.
TABLE 5
Upper Limit of Annual Family Income, by Income Group,
1947-96
(1997 Dollars)
Year |
Lowest
Fifth
|
Second
Fifth
|
Middle
Fifth
|
Fourth
Fifth
|
Lower Limit
|
Top 5%
|
Average
|
1947 |
10,506
|
16,952
|
22,988
|
32,618
|
53,536
|
23,517
|
1967 |
18,167
|
29,823
|
39,992
|
54,827
|
88,094
|
38,914
|
1973 |
20,678
|
34,120
|
47,606
|
65,468
|
102,063
|
46,321
|
1979 |
21,388
|
35,169
|
49,825
|
68,607
|
110,064
|
48,402
|
1989 |
20,714
|
36,242
|
52,810
|
77,079
|
128,093
|
53,723
|
1990 |
20,687
|
35,666
|
51,625
|
75,510
|
125,696
|
  |
1991 |
20,033
|
34,304
|
50,672
|
74,229
|
121,169
|
  |
1992 |
19,119
|
33,946
|
50,335
|
73,271
|
121,275
|
  |
1993 |
18,849
|
33,321
|
50,016
|
74,190
|
125,714
|
  |
1994 |
19,429
|
33,897
|
50,901
|
75,807
|
130,006
|
  |
1995 |
20,083
|
34,738
|
51,588
|
76,101
|
130,228
|
  |
1996 |
20,132
|
35,102
|
52,258
|
77,044
|
130,937
|
54,908
|
Annual
Percent Change |
1947-67 |
2.8
|
2.9
|
2.8
|
2.6
|
2.5
|
2.5
|
1967-73 |
2.2
|
2.3
|
2.9
|
3.0
|
2.5
|
2.9
|
1973-79 |
0.6
|
0.5
|
0.8
|
0.8
|
1.3
|
0.7
|
1979-89 |
-0.3
|
0.3
|
0.6
|
1.2
|
1.5
|
1.0
|
1989-96 |
-0.4
|
-0.5
|
-0.1
|
0.0
|
0.3
|
0.3
|
Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census.
TABLE 6
Persons in Poverty, 1967-96
(Percent of Population)
Year |
Persons with Income:
|
Official
Rate
|
Less than
1/4 the
Median
|
1/4 to 1/2
of the
Median
|
Less
than 1/2 of
the Median
|
1967 |
  |
  |
  |
14.2
|
1973 |
  |
  |
18.9
|
11.1
|
1979 |
6.7
|
13.3
|
20.1
|
11.7
|
1989 |
8.3
|
13.7
|
22.1
|
12.8
|
1990 |
  |
  |
21.8
|
13.5
|
1991 |
  |
  |
22.3
|
14.2
|
1992 |
9.1
|
13.6
|
22.8
|
14.8
|
1993 |
  |
  |
22.8
|
15.1
|
1994 |
  |
  |
22.6
|
14.5
|
1995 |
8.6
|
13.6
|
22.2
|
13.8
|
1996 |
8.6
|
13.7
|
22.3
|
13.7
|
Percentage-point
Change |
1967-73 |
  |
  |
  |
-3.1
|
1973-79 |
  |
  |
1.2
|
0.6
|
1979-89 |
1.6
|
0.4
|
2.0
|
1.1
|
1989-96 |
0.3
|
0.0
|
0.2
|
0.9
|
Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census, published
and unpublished data.
TABLE 7
Changes in the Distribution of Household Wealth*,
1962-97**
Wealth
Class |
Share of Wealth*
|
  |
Change |
1962
|
1983
|
1989
|
1995
|
1997**
|
1962-83
|
1983-89
|
1989-95
|
1989-97**
|
Top
Fifth |
81.0
|
81.3
|
83.5
|
83.7
|
84.3
|
0.4
|
2.2
|
0.2
|
0.8
|
Top
1% |
33.4
|
33.8
|
37.4
|
37.6
|
39.1
|
0.3
|
3.6
|
0.2
|
1.8
|
Next
4% |
21.2
|
22.3
|
21.6
|
22.3
|
22.3
|
1.2
|
-0.8
|
0.7
|
0.7
|
Next
5% |
12.4
|
12.1
|
11.6
|
11.7
|
11.4
|
-0.2
|
-0.5
|
0.1
|
-0.2
|
Next
10% |
14.0
|
13.1
|
13.0
|
12.1
|
11.5
|
-0.9
|
-0.1
|
-0.8
|
-1.5
|
Bottom |
  |
Four-fifths |
19.0
|
18.7
|
16.5
|
16.3
|
15.7
|
-0.4
|
-2.2
|
-0.2
|
-0.8
|
Fourth |
13.4
|
12.6
|
12.3
|
11.5
|
10.8
|
-0.8
|
-0.2
|
-0.8
|
-1.5
|
Middle |
5.4
|
5.2
|
4.8
|
4.5
|
4.4
|
-0.2
|
-0.4
|
-0.3
|
-0.4
|
Second |
0.9
|
1.2
|
0.8
|
0.9
|
1.0
|
0.2
|
-0.3
|
0.0
|
0.1
|
Lowest |
-0.7
|
-0.3
|
-1.5
|
-0.7
|
-0.5
|
0.4
|
-1.2
|
0.8
|
1.0
|
Total |
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
  |
*Net worth.
**1997 figures are estimates.
Source: Authors' analysis of Wolff
(1998).
TABLE 8
Household Assets and Liabilities by Wealth Class,
1962-97*
(Thousands of 1995 Dollars)
Assets
and
Liabilities |
Top 1.0%
|
Next 9%
|
Next 10%
|
Next 20%
|
Middle
20%
|
Bottom
40%
|
Average
|
A.
Stocks** |
1962 |
2,252.4
|
115.2
|
12.8
|
4.1
|
1.1
|
0.3
|
35.8
|
1983 |
1,462.4
|
94.4
|
11.3
|
4.3
|
1.5
|
0.4
|
25.9
|
1989 |
1,103.9
|
121.3
|
23.8
|
8.3
|
3.5
|
0.6
|
27.3
|
1995 |
1,656.9
|
185.0
|
34.8
|
13.2
|
5.3
|
1.1
|
41.1
|
1997* |
2,346.2
|
262.0
|
32.9
|
18.6
|
7.5
|
1.5
|
58.1
|
1962-83 |
-790.0
|
-20.8
|
-1.5
|
0.2
|
0.4
|
0.1
|
-9.9
|
1983-89 |
-358.5
|
26.9
|
12.5
|
4.0
|
2.0
|
0.3
|
1.4
|
1989-95 |
553.0
|
63.7
|
11.0
|
4.9
|
1.8
|
0.5
|
13.8
|
1989-97 |
1,242.3
|
140.7
|
9.1
|
10.3
|
4.0
|
0.9
|
30.8
|
B.
All Other Assets |
1962 |
2,450.3
|
423.1
|
201.0
|
111.8
|
60.5
|
14.4
|
122.2
|
1983 |
5,628.6
|
730.6
|
295.3
|
152.0
|
74.8
|
15.7
|
202.9
|
1989 |
7,823.0
|
803.1
|
317.5
|
173.4
|
83.3
|
18.1
|
240.3
|
1995 |
6,313.0
|
663.8
|
257.3
|
143.3
|
82.3
|
19.3
|
203.2
|
1997* |
7,471.7
|
721.5
|
271.6
|
149.8
|
85.5
|
19.9
|
224.4
|
1962-83 |
3,178.3
|
307.5
|
94.3
|
40.2
|
14.3
|
1.4
|
80.7
|
1983-89 |
2,194.4
|
72.5
|
22.2
|
21.4
|
8.5
|
2.4
|
37.4
|
1989-95 |
-1,510.0
|
-139.3
|
-60.2
|
-30.1
|
-1.0
|
1.2
|
-37.1
|
1989-97 |
-351.3
|
-81.6
|
-45.9
|
-23.6
|
2.2
|
1.9
|
-15.9
|
C.
Total Debt |
1962 |
166.3
|
32.5
|
24.1
|
24.9
|
24.7
|
13.9
|
22.3
|
1983 |
382.5
|
63.6
|
46.0
|
31.3
|
24.4
|
11.7
|
30.0
|
1989 |
417.1
|
85.0
|
45.9
|
41.5
|
31.8
|
22.5
|
39.9
|
1995 |
361.6
|
84.3
|
44.4
|
39.7
|
41.7
|
19.4
|
39.8
|
1997* |
343.5
|
77.5
|
40.9
|
37.7
|
39.6
|
18.4
|
37.8
|
1962-83 |
216.2
|
31.1
|
21.9
|
6.4
|
-0.3
|
-2.2
|
7.7
|
1983-89 |
34.6
|
21.3
|
-0.1
|
10.2
|
7.4
|
10.8
|
9.9
|
1989-95 |
-55.5
|
-0.7
|
-1.5
|
-1.8
|
9.9
|
-3.1
|
-0.1
|
1989-97 |
-73.6
|
-7.4
|
-5.0
|
-3.8
|
7.8
|
-4.1
|
-2.1
|
D.
Net Worth |
1962 |
4,536.3
|
505.7
|
189.7
|
90.9
|
36.8
|
0.7
|
135.7
|
1983 |
6,708.5
|
761.3
|
260.6
|
124.9
|
51.9
|
4.4
|
198.8
|
1989 |
8,509.8
|
839.6
|
295.4
|
140.3
|
55.0
|
-3.8
|
227.7
|
1995 |
7,608.3
|
764.5
|
245.8
|
116.7
|
45.9
|
1.0
|
204.5
|
1997* |
9,474.3
|
905.9
|
277.3
|
130.7
|
53.4
|
3.1
|
244.7
|
1962-83 |
2,172.2
|
255.6
|
70.9
|
34.0
|
15.1
|
3.7
|
63.1
|
1983-89 |
1,801.3
|
78.3
|
34.8
|
15.4
|
3.1
|
-8.2
|
28.9
|
1989-95 |
-901.5
|
-75.1
|
-49.6
|
-23.6
|
-9.1
|
4.8
|
-23.2
|
1989-97 |
964.5
|
66.4
|
-18.1
|
-9.6
|
-1.6
|
6.9
|
17.0
|
*Projections.
**All direct and indirect stock holdings.
Source: Authors' analysis of Wolff (1998).
|