Purchasing Power Parity Estimates for Canada and Implications for Volume Comparisons
Katharine Kemp and Gaston Levesque Statistics Canada
Abstract
Interest in purchasing power parities comes from policy, analytical
and private sector uses and from the widespread recognition that official
market exchange rates are inadequate tools for purposes of comparing price
levels among countries. Governments and international agencies are
increasingly interested in the rankings of countries in terms of their
output for purposes of international comparisons. Academic and private
sector interests continue to explore alternative measures for comparison,
and such direct uses as assessing the relative costs of setting up a
business in different countries, or legal and insurance settlements in
different currencies. A number of PPP measures have been calculated, from
which are derived different results for inter-country price levels and the
reciprocal volume or real comparisons. PPPs as inter-country deflators are
preferable to the exchange rate based comparisons on both conceptual and
empirical grounds. The paper focuses on differences in the Canada/US
comparisons using the multilateral and bilateral studies of the
OECD-EUROSTAT PURCHASING Power Parity Programme, and touches on the
results obtained through the much broader-based World PENN Tables.
Introduction
With increasing globalization and economic interdependence among
countries, the relative performance of countries in terms of economic
output and structure is becoming increasingly important to both governments
and international agencies. The development of new trade associations, such
as the Free Trade Agreement (FTA), the North American Free Trade Agreement
(NAFTA), the Asia-Pacific Economic Co-operation (APEC), General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade, Uruguay round (GATT) have been generating increasing
requirements for macroeconomic tools which can measure, across countries,
output, productivity, investment, and income distributions, to name a few.
Recognition of the importance of spatial comparisons has also been identified
in the 1993 international System of National Accounts “to compare standards
of living, levels of economic development or levels of productivity and also
to compare the price levels in different countries when prices are converted
at exchange rates”. Requirements for such macroeconomic tools emphasize the
importance of the PPPs.
Purchasing power parities interest policy and macroeconomic analysts as
measures of differences in price levels among countries. They can be compared
to market exchange rates and the extent to which a country's currency is
"over" or "under" valued can be monitored over time, in terms of what can
actually be purchased in the other country. Comparison with exchange rates
over time provides a measure of the volatility of currencies on exchange
markets. Private companies can use PPPs to assess how much it would cost
to set up a firm or plant in another country and assist the decision as
to where the most appropriate location would be from an economic perspective.
Similarly, they can be used to determine the type of allowance schedule that
would be appropriate to maintain an employee who is moved from one country
to another. Other uses have been made of the PPPs in valuing insurance claims
or legal settlements that involve parties in different countries. The Estonian
ferry disaster of a few years ago was a good example. Passengers came from
different countries and the financial settlements involved, required currency
conversion by the insurance companies.
A key analytic use for the PPPs is as a set of deflators to convert the
Gross Domestic Product for one or more countries expressed in its own
currency to a set of expenditures expressed in a common currency such as
the currency of a base country or group of countries. By means of this
deflation process, real or volume measures for different countries can be
compared. Converting such volume measures to a per person basis provides
equivalent measurements to rank countries’ output. Beginning in 1993, for
example, the World Bank started publishing the rankings of countries based
on output derived using PPP conversions. Previously exchange rates had been
used as price converters in establishing such rankings. With the change to
the PPPs as currency converters, the share of developing countries in the
"world" economy grew substantially. This was due in large part to the fact
that services tend to cost much less in such developing countries,
contributing to lower PPPs for the GDP as a whole, and resulting in higher
measurements of real output and correspondingly higher GDP per person.
As a further recent example of such uses of the volume comparisons, a
recent paper presented in Ottawa by Professor Robert Summers 1 drawing on
the results of the World PENN Table identified some lines of inquiry which
would be interesting in the Canada/US context as well. These include looking
at output per employed person, leaving out components which he called
“regrettable necessities” (example, defence expenditures) and using only
the remaining GDP components. Given the difference in the share of the GDP
that such expenditures represent in Canada versus the US, this comparison
would raise the relative output of Canada quite a bit. Other suggestions
are to use only current expenditure and omit capital investment from the
comparisons. Investment, which is saving for the future, could be omitted
for some analytic purposes, where current expenditure is of more interest.
Yet another use has recently been demonstrated by Michael Wolfson 2, in which
he is comparing PPP deflated income distributions between Canada and the US,
with interesting findings as to what lies behind the average income in the
two countries. Interest has been increasing as well in developing PPPs at
an industry or production level, as well as the final expenditure level,
as is discussed here. With production- based or industry level PPPs, some
light could be shed on productivity comparisons. This work is at a very
early stage, but is potentially very interesting.
Purchasing power parities (PPPs), which have been under development
since the 1950s, provide price level comparisons among countries from
which can be derived the output measures used for such comparative analysis.
These are theoretically more appropriate intercountry price comparisons than
market exchange rates which can be influenced by many factors in addition to
price levels among countries, such as fuel shortages, political uncertainties,
or the deficit or debt of particular countries. Services, in particular,
are not traded in the same way as goods so that their prices are unlikely
to parallel the exchange rates between countries. Economic theory suggests
that for internationally traded, domestically produced goods and services,
the PPPs and exchange rates will tend to equalize in the long run. Exchange
rates, however, can fluctuate widely in short periods. Sometimes, a country
intentionally devalues its currency, or dramatic shifts can occur due to
exogenous factors (the recent case of Mexico).The exchange rates are,
however, appropriate for some purposes, for example, when analyzing
international capital markets where the exchange rate is the price to be
paid. With the calculation of the PPPs, actual price differences among
countries are identified and these measures and the volume measures derived
from them are much more precise and stable over time. The OECD-EUROSTAT
multilateral PPP program includes all members of the OECD and EUROSTAT
(some differences in the combinations of countries over the period of the
programme) and the most recent PENN World Table includes price and real
output comparisons for about 150 countries. In Canada, we tend to be most
interested in US /Canada comparisons. These studies all present different
results for the US and Canada which are the subject of this discussion.
PPPs measuring world spatial comparisons are analogous to the use and
construction of implicit price indexes in national temporal comparisons
of Gross Domestic Product. They allow expenditures in different countries
to be expressed in the same set of prices (a base set of prices), permitting
volume or real comparisons among countries to be derived. They are measured
at the level of some 220 goods and services, known as the basic heading level.
These micro PPPs are weighted using national expenditures (the weighting
method depends on the particular formula used) to derive a macro PPP for
the GDP in total. Recognized difficulties and differences exist in their
measurement and this paper assesses some of the factors and implications,
which affect the three comparisons, focussing on the reliability of the
Canada/US data.
Three sets of results compare Canada to the US. From the OECD-EUROSTAT
Programme of benchmark studies, a multilateral comparison for the OECD and
EUROSTAT countries provides a relationship for Canada PPPs versus those of
the US. From the same program, separate (direct) bilateral studies for the
US and Canada have been undertaken, drawing out the specifications and
prices which are comparable and representative in these two countries
and using GDP expenditures for only these countries. OECD reference studies
were done in 1980, 1985, 1990, and 1993. The 1996 results are forthcoming
later in 1998. The World PENN Tables, including data for 152 countries
(known as PWT5.6a) also contain comparative data for the US and Canada.
From the OECD-EUROSTAT benchmark studies, time series have been projected
to produce annual PPPs. The OECD Programme publishes time series for the
multilateral comparisons, Statistics Canada publishes time series for the
Canada/US bilateral comparisons and the World PENN Tables publish annual
data for the countries included in their comparisons. Updated data for the
PENN tables are expected in the next few weeks, but for now these tables
for the latest version (PWT5.6a) show time series to 1992.
(Tables and Charts of three comparisons and the exchange rate and
the volume comparisons follow).
Three PPP comparisons and the exchange rate
PPPs Canada/US , Gross Domestic Product
Canadian dollars per US dollar
Year |
OECD multilateral |
OECD bilateral STC (projections) |
PENN Mark 5.6a |
Market Exchange rate |
1980 |
1.27 |
1.21 |
1.15 |
1.17 |
1981 |
1.28 |
1.20 |
1.16 |
1.20 |
1982 |
1.31 |
1.21 |
1.21 |
1.23 |
1983 |
1.32 |
1.24 |
1.22 |
1.23 |
1984 |
1.30 |
1.25 |
1.22 |
1.30 |
1985 |
1.29 |
1.24 |
1.21 |
1.37 |
1986 |
1.29 |
1.23 |
1.21 |
1.39 |
1987 |
1.30 |
1.23 |
1.21 |
1.33 |
1988 |
1.31 |
1.25 |
1.21 |
1.23 |
1989 |
1.32 |
1.23 |
1.21 |
1.18 |
1990 |
1.30 |
1.22 |
1.21 |
1.17 |
1991 |
1.29 |
1.23 |
1.19 |
1.15 |
1992 |
1.28 |
1.23 |
1.18 |
1.21 |
1993 |
1.26 |
1.23 |
|
|
1994 |
1.25 |
1.21 |
|
|
1995 |
1.24 |
1.20 |
|
|
1996 |
1.22 |
|
|
|
Bolded data indicates years of OECD-EUROSTAT benchmark studies 1996
is a projection. The benchmark study is not complete.

Real Gross Domestic Product per head, Canada/US
Derived from:
Year |
OECD multilateral |
OECD Bilateral (projections) |
PENN Mark 5.6a $ Current from PENN data |
PENN adjusted with $Can+$US from OECD Vol 1 |
1980 |
82.3 |
89.7 |
81.08 |
91.28 |
1981 |
83.7 |
90.7 |
81.55 |
92.43 |
1982 |
82.6 |
90.9 |
76.48 |
89.78 |
1983 |
82.7 |
89.4 |
75.52 |
88.99 |
1984 |
83.0 |
87.6 |
74.95 |
87.96 |
1985 |
83.7 |
89.1 |
77.84 |
89.12 |
1986 |
84.4 |
88.4 |
76.77 |
88.95 |
1987 |
84.4 |
90.3 |
79.08 |
91.28 |
1988 |
85.7 |
91.9 |
80.39 |
92.80 |
1989 |
83.6 |
92.7 |
80.35 |
91.65 |
1990 |
81.9 |
88.7 |
78.74 |
88.88 |
1991 |
81.5 |
86.6 |
77.54 |
88.26 |
1992 |
79.1 |
84.1 |
76.29 |
85.67 |
1993 |
78.7 |
82.5 |
|
|
1994 |
78.8 |
82.5 |
|
|
1995 |
78.8 |
82.5 |
|
|
1996 |
77.4 |
80.4 |
|
|
1. Bolded data indicates years of OECD-EUROSTAT benchmark studies.
2. 1996 is a projection. The benchmark study is not yet complete.
3. OECD columns are based on current dollar data; PENN data has been
adjusted to use Canada and US published data from OECD National Accounts,
Vol I.

Description
In general, some axiomatic properties are required in spatial comparisons
(as are also required in time series, depending on the purpose of the price
indexes). For example, the results must be transitive. This means that the
results will be consistent whichever country (or group of countries) is used
as the base. This requirement leads to the use of Fisher formula price ratios
between countries. The Fisher formula also has a drawback for some purposes
in that the derived volume components do not sum to the total volume for the
GDP. For some analysis this is not a serious concern while for other types of
analysis, such consistency in aggregation is important. Another requirement
is factor reversibility; that is, the restatement of the value series deflated
by the PPPs will yield the volume indexes and vice versa, with no remainder.
The OECD multilateral benchmark studies, in which all countries are related
to each other and to the whole, incorporate price and expenditure data from
all the countries included in the comparisons. Comparisons (PPPs) between any
two countries therefore take into account the economic structures of all
countries in the comparison. Each PPP takes into account the market
composition and economic structures of all countries in the comparison,
not just the goods and services on the markets being compared. Complexities
arise from the different markets for consumer and investment and the variety
of goods and services consumed in all the countries. The potential exists
for strong negative or unpredictable correlations between price and quantity
on a cross-country basis. Otherwise stated, a relative price increase between
two countries gives little intuitive feel for what the relative quantity
impact might be, unlike the case in time series where a rise in price for an
item is expected to produce substitution effects, decreasing the quantity
purchased. This phenomenon in a spatial context leads to much wider
differences than are seen in time series between the Laspeyres and Paasche
indexes. (In spatial comparisons, the base or given country’s weights are
used to compile the PPPs)
Following a look at the three sets of results for the Canada /US
comparisons of price and volume, this paper reviews the factors and
their impacts which contribute to the differences in levels and trends
of these PPPs and volume comparisons and describes some initiatives
underway to develop and improve the comparisons. The discussion concerns
the macro level of the PPPs, as well as estimation procedures at more
detailed levels (micro PPPs).
Results
The first table and chart show results of the three Canada/US PPP
comparisons for the period 1981-1995, 3 and the exchange rate, all in
Canadian dollars per US dollar. The PPPs in all cases refer to the
Gross Domestic Product, that is, micro PPPs weighted with GDP expenditure
categories. The first column presents the time series created by the OECD
from its benchmark studies (bolded) for all countries in the multilateral
comparisons. For this multilateral comparison, the PPP projections are
calculated using the ratio of the growth rates of the Implicit Price
Indexes for the Canadian and US GDPs. The years between benchmarks use
forward projections for years near the earlier period and retro-projections
for years nearer the later benchmark. The second column also uses the
results of the OECD benchmark studies in the same years but for the direct
bilateral Canada/US comparisons. In this case, the PPPs are projected and
interpolated in all the intervening years, weighting the PPPs projected
forward and backwards between benchmarks to smooth the transition. Again,
the ratio of the growth rates of the IPIs for Canada and the US are used
as projectors of the PPPs, but at the level of the 55 published categories.
The PENN World Table brings together comparisons in space and time, using
adjustment factors to convert or smooth time series and benchmark data and
to fill in gaps where actual country data are missing. The results cannot
be precisely compared with the OECD studies due to the inclusion of price
and expenditure data for many more countries. Incorporating the economic
structures and prices for 150 countries also affects the relationship
between each pair of countries in the study.
In 1985, the bilateral PPP for Canada (US=100) was 1.24 at the level
of the GDP, compared with the multilateral results of 1.29. In 1990, the
bilateral result was 1.22, compared with multilateral result of 1.30. In
1993, a limited bilateral US/Can study was undertaken, yielding a bilateral
PPP of 1.23 compared to 1.26 for the multilateral result at the level of
GDP. The PENN result was 1.21 in 1985 and 1990, closer to the bilateral
result.
Differences exist between the Canada/US PPPs shown by the OECD-EUROSTAT
multilateral and bilateral benchmark results, with the PPPs from the bilateral
results always lower than the multilateral results. This means, it takes
relatively fewer Canadian dollars in Canada to buy the same amount as one
US dollar purchases in Canada, across all the GDP components, when looking
at the bilateral results than when using the multilateral results. Such
results imply an intuitive result that the closer match of specifications,
prices, markets, and economic structures between the two countries brings
the price comparisons closer together.
In the series calculated for the PENN real output, the current price
estimates have been adjusted, substituting the national published estimates
for GDP in current dollars and population 4 for the data shown in the PENN
Table itself. (PWT 5.6a). This brings the volume measure to levels just
above those for the bilateral study, as would be expected from the slightly
lower PPPs.
A consistent result demonstrated by the three time series of volumes for
Canada relative to the US, is that the output per head has been declining
since 1990. In this period both Canada and the US experienced slowdowns in
growth. If the hypothesis that Canada’s cycle is steeper and slower to
recover, the volume results are plausible.. Some other factors which also
affected the downward trend were downward data revisions in the GDP
expenditure series in Canada and an upward revision to the population
counts, following the 1991 census of population.
PPP estimations
Many empirical considerations, techniques and measurement approaches
are involved in the estimation of the PPPs and the derived volume estimates,
both for the benchmark studies, and for the interpolated time series. The
price index theory and choice of formula issues are largely left for
discussion elsewhere. The purpose of this discussion is to look at more
statistical estimation aspects, which play a critical role in the
comparative result.
It should be noted first, that spatial price comparisons contain
all the same issues and problems that are found in time series, and
usually they are much more complex. As in time series, the measurement
of non-market services (government health and education) causes particular
difficulty. These are measured using the same convention as in time series,
that is, inputs are used to measure outputs. A major shortcoming of the
input-cost approach is that it does not account for differences in
productivity levels among countries. Wage rates and purchased goods
and services as well as capital consumption allowances must be estimated.
Does the doctor’s wage rate in different countries reflect the increased
or decreased productivity of having fewer tools and less equipment to
work with? This is a more serious problem spatially than in time series,
where the equipment and technology would be expected to change more slowly,
not causing major shifts in productivity over time. Spatially, depending on
the countries being compared, wide differences are possible. No adjustment
for intercountry productivity differences are attempted when using these
inputs as proxy measures for the desired outputs, although research is
ongoing in this area. Such adjustments could be very significant,
depending on the GDP component and countries being compared. These are
often referred to as “comparison-resistant” goods. The closer countries’
economic, institutional and market structures are, the less will be the
concern with such issues.
The individual price comparisons among countries are the key element
in the PPP estimations. It is much more difficult to measure price
differences across space than through time. Growth rates for one
country’s market through time are easier to identify than differences
in price levels across markets at a point in time. The latter require
item specifications that are sufficiently representative of a country’s
consumption and at the same time are comparable among countries. The
specifications developed and used in the OECD-EUROSTAT program tend
to be Euro-centric, that is, they are more representative of consumption
in the western European countries than they are of non- European countries,
such as North America, Australia, New Zealand, or Japan.
Bias
Bias concerns statisticians in spatial comparisons even more than
in time series. Bias can be introduced at many different levels. To
increase comparability and reduce possible biases in the comparisons,
the prices incorporated rely on a combination of the following
characteristics and filters. Generic and specific specifications
are used. Specific specifications are quoted in terms of manufacturer
and model number and produce the most exact matches, but are not always
available among countries, or may not be typical of spending patterns.
To fill in gaps, more generic specifications are combined, in which the
characteristics of the item to be priced are described. While these
specifications lead to price estimations for representative goods and
services in most countries, they also embody quality differences between
countries. They may therefore be closer to a unit value comparison,
rather than a measurement of pure price differentials. A third approach
used is the functional equivalence group, specifications which lie
between the specific brand and model (which may not be typical or even
available in certain markets) and the generic specifications which are
not specific enough. The functional equivalence approach identifies more
technical characteristics of the good and a range of “qualities” (high end,
popular-priced, etc.) so that representativity can be improved in
individual countries. To counterbalance bias that may be introduced,
each country prices both typical items in its market and atypical items
which are representative in another country. It is hoped that in combining
the typical item PPP by the atypical one, the result should be reasonably
objective. Possible errors may still arise if the degree of bias is
different in the two directions, due, for example, to the type of outlet
chosen in different countries, or the sample sizes. As is often the case,
the statisticians count on offsetting errors in such comparisons. Bias is
still less of a problem between Canada and the US than among other
countries, however.
Why are these results different
In addition to the price issues raised above, a number of other factors
can influence the results. In the OECD-EUROSTAT comparisons, the individual
PPPs themselves are not revised. However, the extent and timing of revisions
to National Accounts expenditure data can and do affect the volume
comparisons. In Canada, the biggest downward revision in the GDP in at
least 25 years occurred in 1990 (1.2%). This was also the year of a
benchmark study. The results of the census of population conducted every
5 years are introduced when the results become available. For the
intervening years, the population is extrapolated. When the 1991
results became available, the projections were found to be too low,
due to a technical undercounting, and the population counts were raised
by 4% for the census year, and adjusted for the entire series. The effect
of these two revisions was to lower output per person by 5-6%. In the
bilateral time series constructed in Statistics Canada the macro PPPs
are revised through revisions that re-weight the micro PPPs. The accuracy
of population counts in other countries is hard to evaluate. Intuitively,
we expect undercoverage in the United States as a result of the number of
illegal residents in the country. Furthermore, if all the comparisons are
not using data at the same point of timeliness (i.e preliminary or revised
estimates), the results will be different. For example, in the PENN work,
the data on population and GDP may be taken from indirect sources, and
lack the latest revisions, as noted above. Canada has just incorporated
a historical revision based on the 1993 international guidelines for the
System of National Accounts. These are not yet incorporated for countries
in the published OECD version of National Accounts nor are they incorporated
in the PPP comparisons. To the extent that other countries are on a different
time schedule, the comparisons among countries will be less accurate to some
extent.
The accuracy of the National Accounts expenditure data in all countries
in the comparisons and the classification system used for the expenditures
are significant factors. The United States, for example, has never been an
adherent of the System of National Accounts, although they are moving
closer to it. They do special tables for the OECD incorporating some
special classes of expenditure, which are not available in their National
Income and Product Accounts. As a result, some expenditure matches are not
as precise as would be desirable. The PPPs are calculated by the OECD-EUROSTAT
programme using two classifications, the System of National Accounts (SNA)
which is an expenditure classification, and the ICP, the consumption-based
classification used in the United Nations’ International Comparison Program
and incorporated in the PENN tables. These classification differences impact
results for goods and services paid for by government and consumed by
individuals., such as health and education. The ICP results are more
relevant in cases where the analytical emphasis is on the consumer.
The classification system used for the expenditure data, especially
for personal expenditure categories is moving towards the COICOP, that
is, the SNA 1993 classification to be adopted by all countries. This
should eventually improve the consistency of the program among all the
countries.
The definitions and measurements of key concepts embedded
in the National Accounts expenditures and the accuracy of the surveys and
administrative data sources also play a role in the measurements. We have
seen a growing gap between unemployment rates for Canada and the US. This
may reflect definitional differences, undercounts, or measurement tools
to a greater or lesser extent. Again, expectations are that such differences
would be less between the US and Canada than between many other
country comparisons.
Canada/US PPPs
Most of the discussion concerns the two OECD comparisons: Canada/US
from the multilateral comparison and from the bilateral comparison. The
PENN tables are constructed differently, taking into account many more
countries and deriving some estimates using statistical methods rather
than direct price data. Because of the similarity in tastes, markets and
institutions between Canada and the United States, the OECD bilateral
comparison is the most robust comparison. This similarity, which is
reflected in expenditure baskets in both countries minimizes the bias
due to the aggregation process. The range of goods and services consumed
are similar, item specifications can be well matched, similar outlets are
the source of purchases in the two countries, income levels are broadly
similar and statistical classifications and definitions are also very
similar in many instances. This is one set of factors contributing to
the strength of the comparisons for the benchmark studies. Still, the
comparisons are faced with different types of price data banks in the
two countries, where in Canada we are using a much thinner range of
prices and in the US it is a probability sample, not necessarily geared
to a spatial comparison.
Price index theory tells us that an index number problem always exists.
Changing price structures over time and through space alter the trend of
a price index and rebasing of price series is necessary to bring the growth
rates into line. This is true of spatial comparisons as well as time series.
When we compare relative rates of growth using national GDP and those
implied from successive PPP benchmark studies, the change in price
structures both within countries over time and among countries spatially
has the effect that the projected growth rates and new benchmark levels
will not match. The implication is that any projection of the time series
can never be an accurate reflection of new PPP levels. The projection of
the multilateral PPPs, using the growth rates of each country’s GDP
results in apparent discontinuities whenever the benchmark results are
completed. These are not usually severe, but they do represent a conceptual
issue. In the bilateral series the smoothing process was not based on index
number theory, but rather averages out the trend between the benchmark
levels, projecting ahead from the most recent study until the results
are completed. The PPPs using these results have stayed within a narrower
band.
Another point concerns the price indexes embedded in the GDP deflator.
Recent discussion suggests that the CPI for the US has been overstated for
the past few years. One reason cited is that it does not take adequate
account of changes in outlets where consumer purchases are made.
(Department stores to “big box” bulk purchasing outlets, for example).
Other factors mentioned include the micro and macro aggregation formulas,
as well as the treatment of the introduction of new goods and the continuing
issue of quality change adjustments. The suggestion has been made that the
Canadian CPI is less biased upwards. If this hypothesis holds, the lower
rate of inflation in Canada may be at least partly illusory. The comparison
between the two CPIs is, however, bringing down the level of the projected
PPP time series after the latest benchmark study, since the CPI is used to
measure prices for about two-thirds of the GDP. With lower PPPs we would
intuitively expect the reciprocal volume series to rise in Canada relative
to the US. The charts show otherwise. Behind the trend shown are two other
factors: a revision in the population estimates for Canada, which were
raised as a result of the 1991 census, bringing down the GDP per person
as well the downward revision in the GDP estimates for 1990. Combined
these two revisions lowered the GDP per head in Canada by almost 6%.
Thoughts for the future
Although strong support exists to use PPPs rather than market exchange
rates in comparing and analyzing price levels and real or volume comparisons
among countries, it is recognized that improvements are needed at the micro
levels. More confidence can be placed at the macro GDP level in the
comparisons, while some components are more problematic (as is also true
in the time series). Several initiatives are underway. These include the
establishment of a working group for non-European countries to examine and
adapt the specifications and pricing methods particularly in the area of
personal consumption, so as to reflect the tastes and markets of the
different component countries. More analytical resources could be applied
to examine unusual results in different studies for different countries
and try to explain or improve them. Other data sources are becoming available
which can be utilized. These include scanner data, which will provide a much
broader range of price data than are currently collected in most countries.
Additional data are available through the international agencies, for
example, for automobile sales and direct volume measures for items such
as telephone calls, from which PPPs could be implicitly derived. Examination
of both the volume side and the price comparisons may help strengthen the
analysis as well for specific components. Further use can be made of
regression and hedonic methods as is now applied to rents, for example,
as well as the model approach used for parts of construction. Some thought
is being given to productivity adjustment factors where inputs are used,
but this has been an issue difficult to overcome in time series as well.
A number of concerns have been identified in undertaking spatial
comparisons of price and volume among countries. We believe that progress
is possible and that the results will continue to improve, as analysts
continue to identify better approaches to the desired measures, as has
been the case with time series. Finally, the PPP comparisons and their
reciprocal volume measures at aggregated levels are better price converters
than exchange rates and the direct bilateral Canada/US results are believed
to be the most robust.
Foot Notes
1 Robert Summers and Alan Heston, The World distribution
of Wellbeing Dissected, University of Pennsylvania
2 Michael Wolfson and Brian B. Murphy, New views on
inequality trends in Canada and the United States, Monthly Labor Review,
April 1998, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Washington, D.C.
3 The PENN tables are available to 1992; updated
data are expected within weeks.
4 As presented and updated by countries in the
OECD National Accounts, Volume I(1996 edition)
|